At Wednesday night’s second and final Democratic mayoral debate, Mayor de Blasio reiterated his contention that congestion pricing—the use of tolls to discourage driving on particular routes—is “regressive,” meaning it hits lower-income people harder than rich people.
The mayor cited this as a main reason for his opposition to Gov. Cuomo’s call to implement a congestion-pricing scheme to pay for transit upgrades. De Blasio, who has argued with the governor all summer over who bears the blame for subway and bus problems, instead supports a millionaires’ tax to improve that system.
Sal Albanese, the former Brooklyn Councilmember who faced de Blasio in the debate—one of four candidates challenging the mayor in the Democratic primary—said he “supports congestion pricing because it’s irresponsible not to do so.”
The history
Neither the toll nor the tax has a promising legislative history on its side. De Blasio in 2014 tried to get Albany to approve a millionaires’ tax to fund universal pre-kindergarten and then in 2015 asked for a “mansion tax” to offset the cost of renewing the 421-a tax break for developers; neither idea went anywhere. While Cuomo has yet to sketch out any of the details of his congestion pricing idea, a bid by Mayor Bloomberg to create such a tolling system failed to garner enough support in the legislature in 2008 to even get a vote.
De Blasio has been consistent in his skepticism about congestion pricing. He opposed the Bloomberg plan and has been cool for years to the MoveNY proposal, a comprehensive plan to expand the transit system and fund the work with congestion pricing in the form of tolls on the East River Bridges, which are now free.
The claim that congestion pricing is regressive was a factor in the 2008 debate.
The ideas
Any flat fee is going to represent a larger percentage of a low income that of a high one. If the New York Public Library charges me and Jeff Bezos the same 25-cents-a-day fee when we are late returning our respective copies of “Learning to Fly: The Autobiography of Victoria Beckham,” it’s going to take a bigger bite out of my assets than Jeff’s.
So, de Blasio’s logic goes, if you charge a $2.75 toll to drivers whether they are low-income or rich, it’s going to hurt the poor more. And since there are places of the city that are truly underserved by the transit system, some low-income people will have little choice but to stay behind the wheel and pay the toll.
That’s true as far as it goes. But the fact is car owners in general are richer than non-car owners in the city, and low-income people in New York City are much more likely to ride mass transit or car pool than drive a car to work, and are somewhat more likely to do so than wealthier people (see chart below, which is based on this Census data). So while low-income people who do drive could be hurt by the tolls, most low-income people won’t be. What’s more, low-income people will generally benefit more than rich people from the transit improvements funded by the toll because low-income folks depend more on transit.
Share of income group’s commuters who …
Income | Drove alone | Carpooled | Used public transit |
$1 to $9,999 or loss | 14.68% | 4.69% | 58.07% |
$10,000 to $14,999 | 16.01% | 5.19% | 58.71% |
$15,000 to $24,999 | 18.00% | 5.09% | 59.94% |
$25,000 to $34,999 | 22.02% | 5.31% | 58.30% |
$35,000 to $49,999 | 25.67% | 4.65% | 56.88% |
$50,000 to $64,999 | 27.06% | 4.61% | 54.59% |
$65,000 to $74,999 | 28.50% | 4.56% | 54.29% |
$75,000 or more | 23.82% | 3.85% | 52.65% |
It is true, however, that people in different areas of the city could benefit more or less than others from the improved, toll-funded transit system (just as benefits from the current system are uneven). If the MTA uses congestion pricing revenue to create a world-class bus system in the Bronx, the redistributive effect will be obvious because bus riders have lower incomes, on average. If, instead, the MTA improves transit hubs in Midtown, the calculation becomes more complicated, because that work would benefit rich commuters as well as low-income ones.
New York’s Subway System Could Be a Force for Equity and Sustainability
It gets even more complicated if you think about how a range of income classes fare rather than just how the lowest-income groups make out compared with everyone else. If the middle class pays proportionately more than low-income people under the tolling scheme, that is progressive. But if commuting behavior means middle-class workers are more likely to pay the toll than the rich, then there might be a regressive element to the tolls. (And here’s where how one defines “middle class” is key. If your household income is more than $150,000, you’re in the top 13.6 percent of the city, probably not anyone’s idea of middle.)
Remember, though, that the city already charges a regressive sales tax when people buy, say, a new car. There’s also a federal gasoline tax that funds highway and transit projects around the country that charges the same rate to poor and rich alike, and could be considered regressive. So low-income drivers already pay regressive fees. Heck, the fee you pay just to ride the MTA is regressive. A key question would be whether the new mix of charges under the Cuomo plan is more or less regressive than what exists now.
A 2009 RAND study found “there is no single answer to the question, ‘Is congestion pricing equitable?'” but it did draw two conclusions that apply directly to the situation now faced in New York:
If regions spend revenues in ways that benefit low-income individuals, congestion pricing is more likely to be progressive. However, if regions use revenues in a way that benefits all individuals equally, congestion pricing may be, overall, regressive. This is the strongest finding in the economic literature.
Second, even when low-income and other transportation-disadvantaged groups benefit as a whole from congestion pricing, it is very likely that some individuals will still be worse off. These include people with no choice but to drive on congested routes with pricing in effect and those who may have to forgo important trips because they are too expensive. However, many of these same people are also disadvantaged by the current transportation system, and assessments of equity should take this into consideration.
It’s fair to add, of course, that the millionaire’s tax is definitely progressive.
However, congestion pricing has going for it the fact that it incentivizes transit use over driving, and therefore reduces the human and financial impact of traffic, decreases carbon emissions and enlarges the constituency for better transit.
The verdict
Although he didn’t do so Wednesday night, De Blasio has at times in the past few weeks said he’s waiting to see the details of the Cuomo congestion-pricing plan before taking a final position on tolls. That implies what the facts above indicate: that while congestion pricing viewed narrowly can look regressive, and under certain circumstances could even be regressive, it’s not necessarily regressive—especially when it’s funding a transit system that serves millions of people with low- and moderate-incomes.
What the mayor said wasn’t inaccurate so much as incomplete—sort of like those vague announcements the conductor makes about how it’s an “earlier incident” that is ruining your day.
7 thoughts on “Debate Fact Check: Is Congestion Pricing Regressive?”
Thank you for this analysis. The myth that congestion pricing is regressive needs to be debunked.
I disagree with your analysis. Deblasio is right and adding another tax to working New Yorkers in addition to all the other taxes placed on people living in the outer boroughs is just unfair. It’s just another way to segregate Manhattan. Having people too poor to live in Manhattan pay while the Manhattan elite enjoy, for free, all that Manhattan have to offer. Shameful
Toll Roads. What a disgusting concept in a country such as the United States…….
For the most part, de Blasio is still skeptical on congestion pricing. He still feels that it’s a regressive tax and I agree with that. I feel that you are probably one of those who most likely lives within what is going to be the congestion pricing zone and probably won’t be paying for it at all. Statistically, congestion pricing is highly opposed. The only ones who support this idea are the ones who hardly ever drive on a regular basis, which you probably are. Since you brought up the MTA and revenue, I say that we audit the MTA first and see where their existing revenues are going before even giving them any new ones. The reason why is because if we don’t, it will most likely end up the same way as the ones they already have do. Then again, finding out where it’s really going and correcting them on it could make congestion pricing feel unnecessary, and I know anti-car fanatics such as yourself won’t like that.
I own a car, I live in the northwest Bronx and I drive to church in Manhattan every Sunday and to Queens for band practice roughly once a week, and I occasionally have to drive to Queens, Brooklyn or SI for work. So I will pay this fee quite often if it is imposed.
I guess you’ll have to come up with something other than my hypocrisy or fanaticism on which to base your arguments. Good luck!
The plan as it exists is going to kill smaller restaurants and live entertainment venues in the congestion pricing district. Without providing some equitable restrucuring of the plan, most of the aforementioned businesses in the zone will be forced to close their doors. These businesses in this distrct depend on patrons and employees that live outside the zone. One of the unspoken consequences will be its impact on tourism. Tourists do not uniformly come here or can afford to go to expensive restaurants and Broadway shows. Many come here to visit the boutique restaurants and entertainment venues. This plan as it exist will effectively kill most of the entertainment outside of perhaps Broadway.
The plan as it exists is going to kill smaller restaurants and live entertainment venues in the congestion pricing district. Without providing some equitable restructuring of the plan, most of the aforementioned businesses in the zone will be forced to close their doors. These businesses in this district depend on patrons and employees that live outside the zone. One of the unspoken consequences will be its impact on tourism. Tourists do not uniformly come here or can afford to go to expensive restaurants and Broadway shows. Many come here to visit the boutique restaurants and entertainment venues. This plan as it exist will effectively kill most of the entertainment outside of perhaps Broadway.